Economics 576

Macroeconomic Theory and Policy

CLASSICAL/NEOCLASSICAL ECONOMICS

VERY BRIEF GENERAL SUMMARY

 

WHO  WERE  THE  CLASSICAL  ECONOMISTS?   Keynes  used  the   term       classical”  to  refer  to virtually  all orthodox (non-Marxian) economists who  had    written on macroeconomics prior to 1936 (the year of his  General Theory).   More  conventional  modern  terminology  distinguishes between two periods in the development of economic theory  before 1930.   The first, termed classical, is the period  dominated  by the  work of Adam Smith (Wealth of Nations, 1776), David  Ricardo (Principles  of  Political Economy, 1817), and John  Stuart  Mill (Principles of Political Economy, 1848).  The second, termed  the neoclassical period, is represented by such economists as  Alfred Marshall and A. C. Pigou.

 

THEORY BASE: Microeconomic + logical extensions

 

POLICY  PHILOSOPHY:   Laissez faire - Government should   protect competition and the market, otherwise hands off.   Confidence that markets would  self-

correct - eliminate temporary problems.

 

SOME SPECIFICS:  Classical economics assumed that the normal  (or equilibrium)  level  of income at any  point  in time  was  the  full  employment  level.    Why?  Classical  economists generally  accepted  Say's

Law (Supply creates its own demand-named for the French  economist,  J.B. Say, who wrote  in  the early nineteenth century).

 

IMPLICATIONS OF SAY’S LAW:  There would   not   be  general   or  aggregate  over-production. Since any level of production would call forth a level of spending sufficient (in the aggregate) to take that production/output off the market, then overproduction would not be a cause for concern. Insufficient aggregate demand  thus could not  be the cause of significant unemployment  and recession. Finally, wage  flexibility would eliminate any minor, temporary unemployment; price flexibility would clear product markets.

 

     Classical  economists emphasized the  importance

of  real factors.  Money played a role  only  in facilitating   transactions  as  a   medium   of exchange.   Money was seen to be held  only  for the sake of the goods that it could purchase. The  quantity of  money was  seen to  affect the price  level, but  not  relative prices or  real output.

 

A general functional representation of this theoretical system would be as follows:

 

                 (1)  y = y(N)

 

                 dy > 0, but declining a N increases

                 dN

 

                 (2)  dy = W

                      dN   P

 

                 (3)  N = n  æWö

                             èPø

 

                  dN  > o

                  d W 

                   P

 

                  (4)  M = lPy

 

where

 

      Y = output

      N = employment

      W = money wage rate

      P = price level

      M = quantity of money

 l = fraction of income that needs to be

          held in cash balances to satisfy the

          transactions demand for money.

 d = small change in

 

Equation (1) is the aggregate production function of the economy. We  must specify as to its shape only that output increases  less than  in proportion to labor input.  Equation (2)  expresses  the profit  maximization  condition -- that the real wage  equals  the marginal  product of labor.  Equation (3) represents  the  supply curve of labor, and equation (4) is the quantity theory.

 

Keep  in  mind  that the Classical  economists  tended  to  focus     primarily  on  microeconomics.   And  microeconomics  concerns itself with relative prices as opposed to absolute prices (or the price  level).  Thus under the quantity theory, money--which  was seen not to affect relative prices, but only the price level--was of no great consequence. 

 

Generally,   the   Classical   economists   recognized   only a "transactions  demand" for money.  Money was viewed simply  as  a medium of exchange.  So does this preclude saving?  A theory that holds  that all money which is received automatically gets  spent does  not square with the fact that many people save who  do  not themselves  invest.   (Keep in mind that the acts of  saving  and investing are totally distinct phenomena.)  Thus can it be  that the  act of saving (ie., of not spending) might invalidate  Say's Law--meaning   that   there  could  be   insufficient   aggregate demand = too little spending = too much saving = overproduction??

 

 

            The answer to that question is no.  Why not?

 

            (5) S = s(i)       a positive relationship

 

            (6) I = f(i)       an inverse relationship

 

            (7) S = I          equilibrium